1 Introduction
In a world of fast growing population and intercontinental trade relations, the local emergence of new economic centres, on the one hand, and the global competition of existing economic centres, on the other hand, have a major impact on the socioeconomic and political stability of our future world [1]. So, in the last twenty years, there has been an important change in the way geographers and planners have begun to think about the growth and form of cities. The concept of self-organization by which global structures emerge from local actions has gained popularity [2,3, etc.] and the reason for the application of this concept is its ability to indicate explicit interdependent relationships between factors of complicated regional systems and to clarify new ordering derived from a fluctuation in this system. Mathematical and computer models have started to flourish. Such models have the ability to capture the essentials of forces' ‘attractiveness’ and relationships in effect between two cities or between clusters inside cities and to simulate the way these quantities change with time. Analogies with some ecological models are, in some cases, relevant: for example, when two or more species live in proximity and share the same basic requirements, they usually compete for resources, habitat, or territory. Such an analogy has been hardly used in a pioneering model by P. Allen [4].
The Hokkaido prefecture has encoded a serious socio-economic situation, under this problem. Y. Miyata and S. Yamaguchi adapted Allen's model in order to discriminate between a number of roadway systems connecting the main towns with a region [2], so they investigated the possibility of regional redistribution of the population of the Hokkaido prefecture based upon the theory of dynamic self-organization of population distribution. As an illustration of the power of mathematical methods, they consider, in the first part of their work, a simplified system with two towns, adjusting to model proposed by Lotka and Volterra [5], when the competition between two species is depicted without direct reference to the resources they share. The difference of the interpretation between Miyata et al.'s model and the classical Lotka–Volterra model is in the fact that each region has its own potential of resources used by inhabitants of two regions, and the resources are interpreted as services and goods offered in the region. Our purpose here is to revisit this simple system; in the next section, we will describe the model emphasizing its relevance with urban dynamics; in Section 3, we present a complete study of the system, based on the already existing methods in [6] and [7], depending on the location parameters and we will discuss the relevance of the results to the subject completing the mathematical study made by Y. Miyata et al., who used the method of perturbations, which gives no convincing results. The main tools in our study are a Lyapunov function, application of the principle of LaSalle and the discussion of the phase portraits.
2 The model
2.1 Presentation of the model
Miyata et al. present this simple example in order to describe the essence of the theory of dynamic self-organization. So they consider a two-regional population growth model.
The model is represented as follows:
(1) |
population of region i;
carrying capacity of region i;
birth and immigration rate in region i;
βparameter of interdependence between the region i and j;
death and emigration rate in region i.
2.2 Remarks
We have some remarks about interpretation given by the authors concerning the parameters of the model. A better understanding, for us, of the parameters is given as follows:
The general form of an equation describing the evolution of region i, is:
is the growth term;
is the decrease term;
is a growth rate, which is not constant and depends on the two population in a symmetric way:
stands for the resources of region i, expressed in terms of the maximum of individuals that the region i can sustain;
is an efficiency parameter that expresses the interaction between the potential of the region and the population growth;
βrepresents the intensity of resources (namely services and goods) offered in a region used by inhabitants of the other regions;
is the part of resources of region i that is unemployed. It represents the potential of the region i, determining the growth of the population through the efficiency parameter .
We suppose, taking the same β in both equations, that an individual divides his consumption in a proportion that is always even between what exists and what is imported. This hypothesis is obviously questionable.
3 Mathematical study of the model
This section is devoted to the asymptotic behaviour of the solution describing the system (1).
System (1) can be written as a classical competition model:
(2) |
For , the parameters , and satisfy: Hypothesis
This hypothesis has an interpretation in the model: is the crude growth rate of population i when the potential is at its maximum value, namely when the potential is almost zero.
The hypothesis means that this maximum crude growth rate is bigger than the mortality and outmigration rate.
Classical theorems apply, providing existence and uniqueness to the initial-value problem associated to (2) with initial value , with , for , 2. Furthermore, the solutions remains non-negative and exist for all (see [6]).
3.1 Asymptotic behaviour of the solutions of system (2)
3.1.1 Stationary solutions
The stationary solutions of system (2) satisfy the system:
3.1.2 Study of the stability
In the addition to existence of the equilibrium points, we can prove that it is only one globally asymptotically stable point in the positive domain.
The ω-limit set of each non-negative solution of system
(2)
is reduced to one equilibrium point.
Lemma 1
It is a straightforward application of the principle of LaSalle [8], considering the Lyapunov function Proof
(see also [6, p. 270] and [7, p. 28]).
Let us define:
By applying the principle of LaSalle, one has:
As a consequence of this lemma, each non-negative solution of system (2) approaches asymptotically for one of the equilibria , and in what follows we will locate which of the four equilibria is the limit point.
First of all, let us consider the equilibrium point . The linearized system of (2) around this point is:
The stationary point
is repulsive.
Lemma 2
Let us observe that the equilibrium point is the intersection of the two isoclines
Due to the symmetry of system (2), we can suppose that without any loss of generality.
We will make the study of the asymptotic behaviour of solutions in terms of parameter β, which is significant for the model.
If
, we have:
Theorem 3
In this case, the isoclines and intersect in and therefore the equilibrium point should be taken into account. We obtain the stability of equilibria by linearisation of the system (2) around each equilibrium point , , 2, 3, so that and are saddle points and straightforward calculations show that their stable manifolds are and , respectively, this proves (a) and (b). Furthermore is asymptotically stable. Bearing in mind Lemma 1 and Lemma 2, assertion (c) holds. □Proof
Moreover, we have the following result:
For each
, there is a paving of repulsiveness around
.
Lemma 4
With the aim of constructing a paving of repulsiveness around , let be fixed and consider Proof
Then
Choosing
we have
and then, if a solution is in at some instant , there exists for which such solution will be outside for each .
In the same way, we can construct a paving of repulsiveness around . □
If
, we have:
Theorem 5
In this case, isoclines and do not intersect in and therefore there exist three equilibria , and . The linearized systems around and prove that is a saddle point with stable manifold and is locally asymptotically stable. Bearing in mind Lemma 1, assertion (b) follows. □Proof
Moreover, a paving of repulsivity around can be constructed in the same way as in Lemma 4.
Finally, for the third case, similar calculations and standard arguments that can be found in [6] lead to:
If
, the equilibrium point
is in
and we have:
Theorem 6
Moreover, the stable manifold associated to
consists of two orbits converging to
, which divides the positive quadrant into two basins of attraction
and
. All solutions starting in
tend to
and all solutions starting in
tend to
.
4 Conclusion
We said that the model presented in Section 2 was proposed first by Lotka and Volterra, who described the competition between two species for resources they share rather; it is assumed that the presence of each population leads to a depression of its competitor's growth rate. Later on, this model was adjusted in urban dynamics by changing the meaning of the model's variables and parameters. It is now necessary to make an urban interpretation of the results obtained so far.
Hypothesis means that region 2 still the region that has the bigger potential, taking into account the mortality and emigration rate in this region.
When the intensity of resources used by inhabitants of two regions is less strong, , we have an interior steady state, which is stable and which means that each population manages to live in its region and to benefit from the services offered in the other region. But when the intensity is much stronger, , then the solution with initial value , with and converges towards the stationary point . That is the region with the higher potential will be dominant for any initial situation.
For , we have three non-trivial steady state, with two points which are stable. In this case, it is very difficult to verify which one of the populations leaves its area; it depends crucially on the starting advantage each population has. If the initial condition lies in domain , then eventually population 2 leaves to region 1, thus the competition for the use of resources eliminated region 2 and the same if the initial condition lies in domain .
As stated above, it has been shown that all solutions of the system (1) converge, depending on the intensity of the competition parameter β and the initial value, to one equilibrium point; from urban interpretation, we conclude that a small change in the quantity of the intensity of competition influences the result.
This study is the commencement of a large and complete mathematical analysis of a complex models initiated by P. Allen et al. and Myata et al. These models concern n regions and consider that the potentials of each region are variable in time with respect to the global population and its distribution between regions.
Acknowledgments
This work was partially supported by the program ‘Action integrée 212 MA 00 and the JER–IRD’.
The authors are grateful to J.-P. Treuil and Eva Sanchez for discussions leading to the rewriting of this paper.